News

Beyond the retail revolution

Development Policy,Inclusive Economy07 Oct 2009Malcolm Harper

The retail revolution is threatening the livelihoods of millions of farmers in many developing countries. But recent research in India demonstrates that it is possible for small farmers and artisans to be included in modern, integrated value chains.

India is a country of small farmers. About two-thirds of its 1.1 billion people still live in rural areas and farming is the mainstay of their livelihoods. But it is also a country of massive change. India’s call centres and software houses, and the lavish lifestyles of its billionaires may be internationally well known, but for the average urban middle-class Indian, one of the most dramatic changes has been the long-delayed retail revolution. ‘Modern’ retailing – in the form of self-service supermarkets – has come late to India. In attempts to maintain employment, the central and state governments resisted change in retailing for longer than in any other country. With these barriers now broken, however, it is estimated that modern retailing in India is growing at an unprecedented rate of 40% per annum. Similar changes have already taken place in China, Thailand, Latin America and in eastern Europe, but at a somewhat slower pace.

India has become a more open economy since liberalization started at the time of the country’s economic crisis in 1991. Software and services may be India’s most familiar exports, but more traditional merchandise exports such as textiles, basic foodstuffs and other raw materials have also grown dramatically. In 1987, exports accounted for only 6% of gross domestic product, but by 1997 this figure had risen to 11% and by 2007 it had reached 21% and the overall economy had of course also grown massively during that period.

Mismatched chains

How do modern retailing and the growth of exports affect India’s small producers? There is a widening mismatch between traditional small producers and the new multi-branch retailers. In 2008 the International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) warned that India’s farmers were in for a ‘painful shock’ because modern retail chains require large volumes of standardized products, delivered at precise times and to closely specified high quality standards. These large companies also tend to pay slowly. Indian farmers are feeling the impact just like small producers in Malaysia and Thailand did before them. In Malaysia, supermarket chains cut the number of their fresh produce suppliers from 200 to 30 in only two years, according to a 2005 FAO report. In Thailand, one supermarket used to source its produce from 250 local suppliers. It then switched to centralized buying for all its outlets, and within a few years was using fewer suppliers in total than each branch had used before.

In India such changes have already caused serious tensions. Rioters have attacked and burned modern supermarkets, and in Uttar Pradesh (home to 180 million people, including many of India’s poorest small farmers) the state government forbade supermarkets to sell fresh produce. The protesters often march under the hammer and sickle, which is still a powerful political symbol in India. Marx seems to have been right: progress seems inevitably to be associated with increasing inequity.

But India can never retreat to the economic isolation that characterized its first 54 years of independence. There is an urgent need to establish value chains that can include rather than exclude the smallest producers.

Inclusive chains

It is commonly believed that it is very hard profitably to include small producers into modern, integrated value chains. The findings of recent research contradict this assumption. The book Inclusive Value Chains in India (2009) describes 14 case studies of 12 ‘farm to fork’ value chains of fresh vegetables, cotton, rice, shrimps, honey, coffee and broiler chickens, and two non-food products, slippers and incense sticks. None of the chains were large, with an average of 4000 producers each. Six of the chains involved products destined mainly for export markets, while the remainder were for consumption within India.

These value chains were selected because the lead organization in each case – a processor, an external development agency, a supermarket group, a producers’ organization and an exporter – had made a deliberate effort when developing the chain to include small producers. They may have done this for business or for development or ‘social’ reasons, or for a combination of motives, but the results were the same.

Detailed studies of the small producers in the honey and shrimp chains show that they significantly increased both their incomes and assets as a result of being included in the chain. Anecdotal data suggests that the other 12 value chains have been equally beneficial to the small producers. Most, if not all, have significantly improved their economic position since joining the chain. Moreover, the volumes of produce and the numbers of producers involved are growing.

All the value chains are now profitable and are in no way dependent on subsidies or ‘corporate social responsibility’ budgets. This was achieved partly because it had to be. The NGOs and other non-commercial agencies were operating to fixed time scales, and were working towards their own withdrawal. The commercial firms regarded any initial losses as investments in future profitability, and worked to reduce and eliminate them as they would with any new venture. Crucially, they also understood that it was in their interest to develop and maintain a loyal group of suppliers; if suppliers dropped out and had to be replaced, the investment in training and other services would be lost and would have to be repeated with new entrants. Hence, it was good business to ensure that producers were properly remunerated.

Lessons learned

These 14 cases offer a number of valuable lessons.

Appropriate inputs. Many livelihood and value chain interventions are undertaken by institutions that specialize in providing finance, or technical training, or marketing, or administration, or some other service. Such institutions supply the inputs that they have at their disposal, regardless of whether they are actually most seriously needed. The critical inputs provided in the 14 sample cases were chosen on the basis of careful analyses of what was needed and not because of pre-existing institutional prejudices.

Institutional support. The government played a minor role, and in some cases existing government regulations had to be removed in order to allow the value chain to succeed. Government’s role was to do less, not more. Private businesses, both small and large, on the other hand, played a major role as customers, suppliers and often as the initiators of positive and inclusive change. These companies made use of subsidies when they were available, but they were not always necessary; inclusive value chains can be good investments.

Independent management. Small producers are often organized into cooperatives in order to achieve economies of scale and bargaining power. There have been some dramatic successes, such as the Ocean Spray cranberries and Sunmaid raisins cooperatives in the United States, and the Amul milk producers’ societies in India. But overall, the track record of such groups is not good, particularly in ‘developing’ countries, where government interference often replaces good management. The 14 cases showed that such groupings are not always necessary. Groups were involved in seven cases, but in the other seven the producers operated individually. The systems for the flow of inputs, information and products worked effectively under corporate or other independent management, and the producers’ share of the benefits was such as to encourage them to remain in the value chain.

Comparative advantages. Success was achieved through higher quality, rather than by lower prices. Small producers were treated not as the ‘weaker sections’ (as the official Government of India phrase has it) but as economic actors with their own peculiar strengths. Five of the 12 food chains were producing organic crops, in which small producers have particular comparative advantages. Organic cultivation requires an intimate knowledge of the land, which small farmers have, and on-farm labour is often used for weeding or composting, replacing purchased chemicals or other inputs. The emphasis was on exploiting these strengths, for the advantage of all parties, rather than on protecting and thus preserving their weaknesses.

The future

India’s modern retail sector is growing rapidly, but it is still small. Most farmers and artisans continue to sell their produce through traditional channels, local vendors or open markets, and only a few are as yet included in modern value chains of any kind, whether inclusive or not. Yet modern retailing will keep growing, and further research is needed to ascertain the extent to which the benefits found in these case studies can be spread more widely. A number of studies are being carried out, such as by the Center for Tropical Agricultural Research and Education (CATIE) in Costa Rica, sponsored by the Ford Foundation. It is to be hoped that the institutions responsible for promoting value chains will apply what is learned from such research.

There are almost 92 million small farms in India, and many more millions of non-farm artisans. The value chain research discussed here includes a mere 70,000 producers, and does not claim to be representative of India as a whole. The results do show, however, that it is possible for small farmers and artisans to be included and play a profitable part in modern, integrated value chains. Marx was not necessarily right, and progress under capitalism need not be associated with increasing inequity.

References

Harper, M. (2009) Inclusive Value Chains in India: Linking the Smallest Producers to Modern Markets, World Scientific.

Reardon, T. and Gulati, A. (2008) The Rise of Supermarkets and their Development Implications: International Experience and Relevance for India, IFPRI Discussion Paper 752.

Shepherd, A. (2005) The Implications of Supermarket Development for Horticultural Farmers and Traditional Marketing Systems in Asia, FAO.

Dries, L., Reardon, T. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (2004) The rapid rise of supermarkets in Central and Eastern Europe: Implications for the agrifood sector and rural development. Development Policy Review 22(5): 525-556.

Footnotes

Unfortunately, due to the age of this contribution and several migrations to online content management systems, the footnotes in the text may have been lost. The footnotes below are listed in its original order of appearance in text.
  1. The average farm size (1.4 ha in 1996) is decreasing as the population grows and family land is shared between succeeding generations. Many rural people own no land at all. Some of these work for those who do have land, while millions of artisans and self-employed craftsmen and women earn a living as handloom weavers, shoemakers or blacksmiths.
  2. Reardon, T. and Gulati, A. (2008) The Rise of Supermarkets and their Development Implications: International Experience and Relevance for India, Discussion Paper 752. IFPRI, Washington, DC. View PDF
  3. Dries, L., Reardon, T. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (2004) The rapid rise of supermarkets in Central and Eastern Europe: Implications for the agrifood sector and rural development. Development Policy Review 22(5): 525-556.
  4. Data from World Bank World Development Indicators, accessed June 2009.
  5. Reardon, T. and Gulati, A. (2008) The Rise of Supermarkets and their Development Implications, Discussion Paper 752. IFPRI, Washington DC.
  6. Shepherd, A. (2005) The Implications of Supermarket Development for Horticultural Farmers and Traditional Marketing Systems in Asia, FAO, Rome.
  7. Harper, (2009) Inclusive Value Chains in India: Linking the Smallest Producers to Modern Markets, World Scientific Publishers, Singapore.
  8. Seven of the value chains were initiated by large for-profit national firms, one by a multinational business, one by a local church and the rest by NGOs. Seven required initial assistance from foreign or local sources, but the initial setup costs for the other seven were seen as normal business investments. In every case, the producers were already producing the basic product, or something similar. The role of the lead organization was to improve the working of the chain, through a variety of changes in design, quality, varieties, marketing arrangements, extension services and finance.