News

When growth is empty – Towards an inclusive economics

Development Policy10 Jun 2011Nicky Pouw

The pursuit of endless growth and the ensuing global financial crisis have eroded public trust in economic policy. As a result, an increasing number of economists are advocating a more inclusive global economy.

The recent financial crisis has exposed the weaknesses of the market-driven approach to social and economic policy. Not surprisingly, the failure of the liberalized, efficiency-driven system has policy makers around the world looking for new ways of organizing their social economies. For decades, economists from different schools of thought have been calling for the global economic system to be revised, but often in isolation from one another. The financial crisis, however, seems to have united economists and philosophers in an effort to promote a more inclusive global economy.

The financial crisis has also convinced many economists to self-reflect and go back to the drawing board. Orthodox economists from the neoclassical school, whose ideas rest on the assumption that there is perfect market equilibrium, fear that the strength of the discipline will be put at risk. But many others, including leading economists such as Amartya Sen, Joseph Stiglitz, Dani Rodrik, Jeffrey Sachs and Paul Krugman, argue that ethics and morality, and culture and context, need to be reintroduced into economics.

New way of thinking

Paul Krugman, 2008 Nobel laureate in economics, gave his New York Times article from 2 September 2009 the heading ‘How Did Economists Get It So Wrong?’ He argued that economists had failed to predict the global economic crisis because they were ‘mistaking beauty for truth’ in their mathematical models. The economics profession had been blind to ‘the very possibility of catastrophic failures in a market economy’.This critique stands out as one coming from the heart of the discipline itself. It follows a longer series of self-reflections in works by development economists, such as Stiglitz’s 2002 book Globalization and Its Discontents, and Rodrik’s 2004 book Rethinking Growth Policies in the Developing World. They warned against the pitfalls of economic development ‘blueprints’.

Sen, ethical guide for many development economists, has urged for the re-evaluation of the ethics of economics and a revision of its underlying concepts and axioms from a more inclusive perspective, particularly in Development as Freedom, published in 1999, and most recently in The Idea of Justice, published in 2009. Likewise, US economist Sachs stresses in his 2010 article ‘Rethinking Macroeconomics’, published in issue 18 of The Broker, ‘that future prosperity will require basic reforms in global macroeconomic governance [and] new ways of thinking’.

These calls for a more inclusive economics and a rethinking of the field’s underlying concepts also found voice in a landmark report, The Growth Report: Strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive Development, published in 2008 by the Commission on Growth and Development (CGD). The commission was formed in 2006. Chaired by Nobel laureate Michael Spence and Danny Leipziger, former vice-president of the World Bank’s Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Network, the commission’s aim was to gather over a four-year period ‘the best understanding there was about the policies and strategies that underlay rapid and sustained economic growth and poverty reduction’. The findings were published in this final report, intended for its audience, ‘the leaders of developing countries’.

The report states that ‘growth strategies cannot succeed without a commitment to equality of opportunity, giving everyone a fair chance to enjoy the fruits of growth’. 1 Inclusive growth should be achieved through policies that stimulate productivity in combination with new employment opportunities. Persistent inequalities, such as gender inequality, argues Ravi Kanbur, one of the contributors to the report, should be addressed from the outset as they tend to undermine the sustainability of economic growth. But it is difficult to pinpoint the market-based economic model’s sore spot because social relations are not reflected in economic models. By the same token, economic analysis does not factor in exclusionary practices or discrimination.

Attempts to re-think economic policy making were also made in 2008 by French President Nicolas Sarkozy. He commissioned three leading economists – Nobel laureates Stiglitz and Sen, and Jean-Paul Fitoussi of the Institut d’études politiques de Paris – to lead a major inquiry into the development of new measures of economic performance and social progress. The central message of the 2009 report by the Stiglitz Commission, as it became known, was that economists should re-think both economic policy making and economic accounting from a broader concept of welfare. The report went a step further than the CGD report by proposing a more encompassing welfare concept and suggesting that economic accounting frameworks be reconsidered. Similar studies have been conducted in the Netherlands by the Social Cultural Planning Bureau (SCP) and the Central Bureau of Planning (CPB). 2

If a broader concept of welfare is to guide economics, the report recommends developing new measures of economic performance to complement the standard gross domestic product measure, which has many shortcomings. For one, its focus on economic growth is narrow (more growth is always better). 3 Indeed, The Stiglitz Commission’s report re-ignited the debate on the limits of growth and the related measures of economic performance among economists in the worlds of academia and policy making.

It is highly unlikely, however, that a new measure will be enough to steer economists away from the perpetual growth mantra. Economists need to urgently scrutinize the field’s underlying concepts and axioms, and subsequently lay the foundations for a more inclusive economics framework and way of thinking.

The perils of growth

The standard neoliberal recipe of stable capital markets, privatization and liberalization, combined since the 1990s with donor-led national poverty reduction strategy programmes, has yielded precious little so far. But progress has been made in some former low-income countries. The growing middle classes of India and China, for example, attest to a rise in average per capita income and improved food security. This progress appears to be mainly the result of economic policies that have little to do with the Washington Consensus, however, which favours liberalization and deregulation.

Indeed, governments in countries such as India and China have chosen to pursue their own development strategies. Targeted, government-controlled reform policies – including high savings and government investments, together with foreign direct investment – have fuelled growth in concentrated areas in these countries. Average incomes have also grown substantially in these countries, thanks to more recent policies that stimulate migration and remittances, increased social spending, industrial relocation to poorer areas and investment in agricultural production.

Some regions in China and India have benefited more than others, however, with far-reaching consequences for those that have ended up with the short end of the stick. The latter have suffered irreversible losses of livelihood and natural resources. There has been massive displacement of minority groups searching for income opportunities. Social services in cities, unable to keep pace with the rate of urbanization, are inadequate. This is widening the inequality gap.

Rapid growth has also placed increasing pressure on the natural environment. Climate change and ecological distress affect people who depend on natural resources for their livelihoods the most, such as farmers and fishermen. They have no other income options, because rural economies usually lack local labour and capital markets. Migration to urban hubs does not always generate sufficient remittances to compensate for the loss of labour for rural families. The multiple roles women fulfil and time constraints limit their ability to cope at a household level. This exposes them to increased risk and hardship.

High growth figures in countries such as China and India generally downplay – or worse, brush aside – inequality and environmental damage as inevitable by-products of economic success. Increased productivity and new employment opportunities do increase welfare on the whole, but they alone do not have the power to reduce inequality or ensure environmental sustainability for all. Growth, of any kind, frees sorely needed money for investment. What to invest in, remains subject to the will of those in power.

Building blocks of inclusive economics

Those who advocate a more inclusive perspective in economics do so on the basis of the realization that two key changes have taken place in economies worldwide. This is the conclusion of the Stiglitz Commission’s 2009 report, The Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress Revisited. 4

First, the authors take into account the changing structure of national economies worldwide. New sectors are emerging, such as highly specialized private medical and financial services. And old sectors, such as manufacturing, are either disappearing or are being relocated. The relationship between paid and unpaid economic activities, and between the formal and informal economy, is changing.

New national accounting tools are needed to capture the growing role of imputed values 5 in the economic system. Imputed values are the estimated values of scarce resources for which there is no market or market price, such as household goods and services. For example, the output of education and medical services, provided by the government, has always been badly measured. Likewise, the economic value of non-market goods and services (for example, household production or community services), while increasingly recognized, is difficult to measure in monetary terms. The United Nations Statistics Division is seeking ways to integrate values of household production and the informal economy into systems of national accounting. 6

Second, the authors, and other proponents of a more inclusive approach to economics, recognize the changing social values assigned to economic performance and our legacy to future generations. Recognizing different cultural values, social justice, democracy in a broad sense, environmental sustainability and real opportunities for the poor are gradually becoming central issues in the global public media. The CDG report and the Stiglitz Commission’s report are only two examples of the call for a more pragmatic, reality-based approach to economics and an increased focus on the morals and ethics of growth.

We are all agents of well-being

Reuters / Stephen Hird

A more inclusive perspective in economics has to ensure that people are part of the equation again, in the tradition of Hungarian political economist Karl Polanyi and social economists such as Mark Granovetter and Richard Swedberg. It must recognize that, ultimately, people’s decisions steer the ‘invisible hand’ balancing the economy in flexible states of equilibrium. Indeed, real people, with different interests and operating at different levels of power, are part of the economic process. They make economic decisions about the consumption, production and distribution of scarce resources, and they, in turn, are affected by decisions made by others.

This ‘double movement’ in economics deserves more attention. The phrase was coined by Polanyi in his seminal work The Great Transformation, published in 1944. It originally referred to the rising market society and government response to this in the form of social protection. The concept has renewed significance in light of today’s global economies because though free competition in the global market may stimulate growth, some people are undesirably affected by economic growth and need protection.

In economics people are ascribed agency, the capability to solve economic problems. Individual characteristics, social identity, power relations and institutional contexts influence people’s capabilities, and thus their agency. Moreover, economic agents perform multiple roles. They can be producers, consumers, distributors or recipients 7 in the market and public domain. Economic agents need to reconcile these different roles, which confront them with a series of constraints (for example, budget, time, cultural norms, politics). A broader definition of the economy would capture the economic realities of people on the ground. It would also shed more light on the socially and politically determined roles and capabilities of economic agents.

In the most common definition of the economy, the market allocates scarce resources. Polanyi’s definition, however, can be described as a process in which economic agents – producers and consumers – allocate these resources to other economic agents. This broader definition includes factors beyond the market, such as the state and individuals (in the form of households or society, for example). It also sheds light on the state’s role in redistributing public goods and services, as well as exchanges in kind by households, communities and other groups of people. The fact that market exchange is not the only determinant of well-being is one of the things that characterizes inclusive economics.

Well-being, not welfare

Human well-being should be the central goal of economic performance and social progress, and not welfare, which comes down to how someone is faring economically. 8 This premise builds on the broader definitions of poverty, which have been debated ever since Peter Townsend developed his ‘basic needs’ approach in the late 1970s.

The ‘basic needs’ concept, in turn, inspired the Human Development Index, designed by economist Mahbub ul Haq and his team of colleagues in the late 1980s. 9 Most economists in favour of inclusive economics also argue for an even more comprehensive and subjective measure of well-being than this index, as promoted by the United Nations and Sen. More recently, Allister McGregor, professor at the Institute for Development Studies in the United Kingdom, has promoted an approach to development centred on well-being. 10

Well-being consists of material wealth, social relationships (including environmental) and psychological security. Well-being, and how it is perceived, is rooted in culture. Together, these three dimensions determine a person’s value system and economic choices.

Well-being also has a distinct social dimension. Social well-being emerges out of a negotiation process in which people give up part of their individual well-being for the greater social good. Social well-being thus can consist of more than its individual parts. Economic policies promoting equality and sustainability should therefore not focus only on increasing the average level of welfare. They should also focus on the marginalized and excluded, and give them a voice in this negotiation process.

Exchanges between individual and social well-being are continuously being renegotiated in a democratic system. They determine how individual well-being is redistributed, for example through the tax system, social services (for example, housing, education and health), unemployment benefits and pension schemes.

By contrast, in neoclassical economics, social welfare is the sum total of individual welfare augmented by individual consumption. In other words, when individuals receive higher incomes and increase their consumption, average welfare increases. The means for achieving higher income and growth easily become an end in themselves when other dimensions of well-being are discarded.

The recent crisis, however, has shown that when growth reaches a certain point, it can become ‘empty’ growth. Empty growth no longer represents an increase in real value, as the subprime lending and trading of mortgages-backed securities in the United States have illustrated. Indeed, it undermines the stability of real growth and burdens people with (more) risk and uncertainty. Structural inequities in the social, political or economic system mean that some feel this burden more than others.

The recent crisis has also eroded public trust in financial markets. The pursuit of endless growth has created risk, uncertainty and a lack of trust – all undesirable aspects for any economy, whether it is growing or not. So more growth needs to be complemented by something else – by technological improvements to increase real value, for example. This implies the need for social investment (in education and human capabilities, for example, since knowledge fuels technological change).

Governments play a key role in figuring out which aspects of well-being to protect or invest in. They seek the public’s consent for this through a ‘social contract’. A social contract is a continuously renegotiated process of mutual consent between society and the state. It establishes order and rules in society and clarifies for citizens what their duties are.

Governments must therefore encourage public debate and actively include the excluded. The excluded deserve the opportunity to defend their well-being and demand investments in their capabilities so they can address priorities in their lives. This is a point repeatedly made by leading economists, such as Sen in The Idea of Justice and the Stiglitz Commission in its 2009 report. However, a broader welfare concept in itself will not shed light on the origins of social inclusion and exclusion. We need to look beyond the market and the state to understand how social relationships shape economic decisions.

Social provisioning

Reuters / Bruno Domingos

It is not only the marketor the state that generates human well-being. Social provisioning – a term often used to distinguish between goods generated by unpaid economic activities and goods provided by the market or state – also contributes to human well-being. Think, for example, of household and community production, and the distribution of unpaid goods and services. These activities fall outside the scope of standard neoclassical economics because households and communities are primarily seen as ‘consumers’ in the economic system. 11

Social provisioning tasks are typically interdependent and closely embedded in social relations. Examples are cooking a meal, taking care of the sick and elderly, cooperating to work on each other’s land, voluntary community work to maintain green areas or roads, and support arrangements. The social ties between people provide an organized social setting in which people cooperate, provide care and organize support to generate individual and social well-being.

Informal arrangements in these social settings determine who has access to and control over scarce resources and capital input. These resources are often shared. A group of voluntary community workers, for example, may share tools while maintaining parks and playgrounds. A rural community may work together on communal land. Fishing communities along the southern coast of India may share the same fishing grounds. Its people’s social identity determines access and ownership of these fishing grounds in the absence of formal market and government regulations. Individual families may even choose to go temporarily poor during the lean season by diminishing their daily fish catch to sustain fish stocks, and their way of living, in the long run.

Self-fulfilment and reciprocity lead people to engage in social provisioning, not just individual gain. Community membership, as the fishing example illustrates, is regarded as the most important asset. These kinds of economic decisions can only be understood if economic value is interpreted from a broader perspective of well-being. Family relations entail a moral obligation to behave socially, but racial, ethnic, class or religious ties may also play a role.

Apart from increasing material well-being, Social provisioning can strengthen social cohesion and psychological well-being. People may value community collaboration because it gives them a sense of identity or security. Many participatory poverty studies see the lack of cooperation between members of rural communities as a sign of ‘poverty’, when poverty is defined according to the perspective of local people themselves. 12

Stephen Marglin, professor of economics at Harvard University, argues in his 2007 book The Dismal Science: How Thinking Like an Economist Undermines Community that economic growth can erode the sense of community as well if individual interests are behind growth. Self-interest taken to the extreme inevitably leads to economic instability, as the recent crisis so pointedly demonstrated. Social provisioning activities in a global economy increasingly transgress national boundaries. Think, for example of migrants sending money home or investing in their former communities.

A more inclusive economic framework needs to do the following:

  • Make social provisioning activities and outcomes visible in the economic system, alongside state and market provisioning
  • Regard contributions to well-being in its multiple dimensions
  • Look into interrelationships and trade-offs between the market and non-market domains

The economic value of socially and state provided goods and services is difficult to measure. There is no ready market price for these inputs and outputs. Other measures and indicators need to be designed to assess their value or they will not be included in economic analyses. Monetary and non-monetary measures should be used to estimate these interrelationships, and the cultural values of non-market activities need to be explored in more detail.

Economic performance

The above notions of well-being and social provisioning automatically alter the way we think about economic performance. Economic performance entails more than just the rate of economic growth. It is rooted in the combined set-up and arrangements of state, market and social provisioning activities. The performance of any economy can and should also be thought of in terms of its ability to enhance social equity and the sustainable use of its resources. 13

Economists must take a more moral or ethical stance with regard to social and political relationships, including gender relationships, as they shape economic processes and outcomes in an unequal manner. Clear choices must be made about the desired type of growth and the use of scarce resources as well.

How scarce resources are used is no longer only a question of efficiency. It is also a question of social equity and environmental sustainability. In other words, ‘efficiency’ is itself subjective. Take, for example, people’s notions of how much time or space is needed to live well, or new indicators, such as ‘the quality of life indicator’. Economic analyses should use these factors as well, and not only monetary indicators.

Deepa Narayan, project leader of Moving out of Poverty, a 15-country World Bank study aiming to ‘bring a bottom-up perspective to policy debates about wealth creation’, reports that in India the role of local democracy and governance is vital in enabling people to climb up the ‘ladder of life’ and to enhance equality. She has constructed a ‘mobility of the poor’ index based on a large database of life histories. These histories tell the stories of people who have either climbed out of poverty, fallen into poverty or whose situation has remained stagnant (whether poor or rich) over a 10-year period. She then asked them which factors helped them to move out of poverty. Local democracy and family support were cited as the most valuable factors that helped people and communities to make lasting progress in life.

Another example using non-monetary indicators in economic analyses is that of economists joining forces with ecologists. The Swedish ecologist Johan Rockström and his multidisciplinary team of researchers have identified nine planetary boundaries in ecological systems. If human activity goes beyond any of these boundaries, it will cause irreversible loss to these systems.

For example, in order to sustain global freshwater resources for future human well-being, countries would have to choose an economic growth path that keeps us within the proposed planetary boundary of 4,000 km3 usage of water per year. Given the current rate of 2,600 km3 under present economic activity, this is still within the safety zone. However, the United Nation’s world population growth estimates anticipate a rise from 6.9 billion people in 2010 to 9.1 billion in 2050.

Needless to say, this will put more pressure on freshwater resources. Economic growth and its related human activities is one of the key variables impacting climate change and water use. So it stands to reason that we will run out of fresh water at some point if countries continue to grow economically at the current pace. 14 It is the poor and marginalized in particular that are currently deprived of access to safe drinking water.

From a well-being perspective, investments in individual capabilities as well as physical and social infrastructure could mitigate such risks. Likewise, this perspective sees investments in environmental sustainability as an investment in future well-being, unlike the neoclassical growth theory, which views them as an expense. 15 The freshwater resources example shows how environmental indicators can play a meaningful role in economic analysis. 16

Sen argued in 2000 that economic growth should become instrumental in achieving human well-being, rather than an end in itself. The expansion of people’s freedom to choose is a virtue in its own right. However, the real choices that people have are undermined by more powerful economic agents, which control social, political and economic institutions.

Sen therefore recently broadened the discussion on economic growth to include social justice concerns in The Idea of Justice. The question economists should now ask is whether a society wants growth at all costs? One answer is to develop a more inclusive economics framework, and not only new proposals for generating growth, new employment policies and new ways of measuring performance. It is not enough for economists to simply build better models. They need to collaborate with historians, geographers, philosophers and others in order to make sound ethical choices about how the economy should be organized.

Economic accounting frameworks

Whether we opt for consumption-based growth, export-led growth, ‘green growth’ or more well-being clearly matters to the social and environmental ‘footprint’ we leave behind to future generations. The type of growth path followed is decided upon by people in the driving seat  – economic planners and decision makers.

Economic models and accounting frameworks form an important part of their toolkit. The System of National Accounts (SNA), for which the international statistical standards to measure the economy are set by the United Nations, underlies most economic models and planning devices at the national level. It specifies all monetary flows embedded in market relationships between economic agents, including households, businesses and the government.

The SNA comprises an integrated set of macroeconomic accounts, balance sheets and tables. These are based on internationally agreed economic concepts, classifications and accounting rules within the United Nations framework (UN Statistics Division 2010). The SNA, from time to time, is changed to accommodate structural changes in the economy and theoretical principles.

At the core of each country’s National Account (NA) is the Social Accounting Framework (SAM). The SAM is more extensive than the NA as it can include non-national accounting flows (for example, capital and labour). The SAMs are used to add more detail to the underlying relationships between economic agents, sectors and scarce resources. As such, they inform important economic models, including the Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) models and Input-Output (IO) models. 17

A more inclusive perspective implies at least three modifications to the standard SAM. Together, these result in an Inclusive Economy Matrix (IEM). 18 First, households (and the individuals in these households) and communities 19 are included in the IEM as loci where social provisioning (unpaid production of goods and services) takes place. The IEM can then be used to model the implications of economic change within the market, private and social, and state domain of the economy, and how trade-offs between the three take place. Qualitative information on gender roles in the economy in combination with quantitative time-use studies of household production, for example (apart from wage data), can provide useful complementary input into the modelling and analysis of female labour market participation. 20

Second, in addition to the standard inclusion of land, labour and capital as scarce resources, other natural resources and time are included in the IEM. As a result, not only their monetary value features in economic analyses, but also their distribution, location and availability in time. This facilitates the analysis of resource use and inter-agent distribution as part of economic planning.

Third, the equations specified to model the interrelations in the IEM can be solved subject to a range of more objective (for example, cost efficiency) or subjective (for example, social equity, environmental sustainability) optimization rules, or both, since these can now be shown to be internally consistent with the framework. In this way, it is expected that the objective of economic accounting and planning will shift more towards comparing and contrasting alternative growth scenarios, rather than predicting maximum attainable growth rates at two digits behind the decimal point. Type of growth matters as much as rate of growth to future economic performance and social progress. 

References

Becker, G. (1991) A Treatise on the Family, Harvard University Press.
Commission on Growth and Development (2008) The Growth Report: Strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive Development. The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, and The World Bank
CPB (2009) Broad Welfare and National Income. Ministerial Policy Report, September.
ECA (2002) A Conceptual and Analytical Framework for Gender Mainstreaming in National Accounts and National Budgets. Ethiopia: United Nations Economic Commission for Africa.
Gough, I. and J.A. McGregor (2007) Well-being in Developing Countries. From Theory to Research, Cambridge University Press.
Granovetter, M. and R. Swedberg (eds) (2011) The Sociology of Economic Life. Westview Press.
Krugman, P. (2009) How Did Economists Get It So Wrong? The New York Times, September 6.
Marglin, S. (2008) The Dismal Science. How Thinking like an Economist Undermines Community, Harvard University Press.
Narayan, D. (2002) Voices of the Poor. Can Anyone Hear Us? The World Bank.
Narayan, D. (ed) (2009) Moving out of Poverty. The Promise of Empowerment and Democracy in India. Palgrave MacMillan.
Nussbaum, M. (2004) Beyond the Social Contract: Capabilities and Social Justice. Oxford Development Studies, 32(1): pp. 3-18.
Polanyi, K. (1957) The Great Transformation. Beacon Press.
Pouw, N.R.M. (2008) The Characterization and Monitoring of Poverty. The Case of smallholder farmers in Uganda. Thela Thesis.
Pouw, N.R.M. (2011) Toward More Inclusive Economics. Some Conceptual and Theoretical Departure Points. Presentation at the Annual Conference of the Eastern Economics Association (EEA) of the American Economics Association (AEA), New York: 24-27 February 2011.
Power, M. (2004) Social provisioning as a starting point for feminist economics. Feminist Economics, 10(3): pp. 3-19.
Rockström, J., et al. (2009) A Safe Operating Space for Humanity. Nature, 461(24 September): pp. 472-475.
Rodrik, D. (2004) Rethinking Growth Policies in the Developing World. UNU-Wider Annual Lecture, Stockholm: 5 November.
Sachs, J. (2010) Rethinking Macroeconomics. The Broker 18, February, pp. 14-16.
Sen, A. (2000) Development as Freedom. Anchor Books.
Sen, A. (2010) The Idea of Justice. Penguin Books.
Stiglitz, J. (2002) Globalization and its Discontents. Penguin Books.
Stiglitz, J., A. Sen and J.-P. Fitoussi (2009) The Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress Revisited. Reflections and Overview. Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress, September.
UNIFEM (2009) A User’s Guide to Measuring Gender-Sensitive Basic Service Delivery. Geneva: United Nations Development Programme.
UN Statistics Division (2010), website on the System of National Accounts, accessed 10 November 2010.

Footnotes

1. Commission on Growth and Development (2008) The Growth Report: Strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive Development. The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, and The World Bank, p.7.
2. See Ministerial Policy Report on ‘Broad Welfare and National Income, CPB September 2009.
3. See the article ‘Cutting to the Core’ in The Broker, issue 19, April 2010.
4. See Stiglitz, J., Sen, A. and Fitoussi, J.P. (2009) The Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress Revisited. Reflections and Overview. Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress.
5. Imputed values are estimated values of scarce resources for which there is no ready market and thus no market price (for example household goods and services, natural resources).
6. For example, the first National Satellite Account for Household Production (NSAHP) was launched in 2002 in South Africa. This system is considered exemplary for the African region and ministerial discussions on implementing it in other African countries (e.g. Tanzania and Uganda) are on-going. (Economic Commission for Africa 2002).
7. The economic term allocation covers production, consumption and distribution.
8. For example, see Sen 2000 and 2010; Nussbaum 2004; Gough and McGregor 2007.
9. This team included Amartya Sen, Frances Stewart, Paul Streeten, Gustav Ranis, Keith Griffin, Sudhir Anand and Meghnad Desai.
10. The human well-being approach featured in issue 19 of The Broker, April 2010.
11. An exception to this are neoclassical models of the household that do assign economic value to household production, but without regarding the social and emotional values involved (see Gary Becker’s A Treatise on the Family, published in 1991) .
12. See, for example, Narayan 2002 and Pouw 2008.
13. See also the recent article by Praful Bidwai, ‘From GDPism toGenuine Equity’ in issue 20/21 of The Broker published in July 2010, in which he argues for a new economics that incorporates solutions to environmental and social problems.
14. In total, Rockström and his team at the Stockholm Resilience Centre have identified nine planetary processes (and boundaries) that set the preconditions of human life on earth, including the 1. the ocean, 2. land, 3. biodiversity, 4. climate change, 5. nitrogen, 6. phosphorus, 7. chemical pollution, 8. air pollution and 9. fresh water resources  (Rockström 2009).
15. It is not only very difficult to estimate the costs of environmental degradation as many of these costs tend to unfold over time and stand subject to change in climate conditions. It also has a tendency to see the commodification of common property resources as the solution to environmental sustainability.
16. See also Stiglitz et al. 2009.
17. CGE models consist of an interrelated set of equations and a consistent database that together make it possible to analyze the economy’s response to a policy change. The equations are informed by neoclassical theory. IO models depict an economy’s inter-industry relations, as well as a national economy’s consumers, government and foreign suppliers.
18. For a detailed explanation, see Pouw, N.R.M. (2011) Toward More Inclusive Economics. Some Conceptual and Theoretical Departure Points, presentation at the Annual Conference of the Eastern Economics Association (EEA) of the American Economics Association (AEA), New York: 24-27 February 2011.
19. Instead of ‘communities’, the term socio-economic groups can be opted  for to signify collective arrangements of social provisioning that are embedded  in social ties.
20. See UNIFEM (2009) A Users Guide to Measuring Gender-Sensitive Basic Service Delivery. United Nations Development Programme.